• Nebyly nalezeny žádné výsledky

VINER’S MODEL OF CUSTOMS UNION

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2023

Podíl "VINER’S MODEL OF CUSTOMS UNION"

Copied!
73
0
0

Načítání.... (zobrazit plný text nyní)

Fulltext

(1)

Lecture 3

Topic 3, Economics of Customs Union

VINER’S MODEL OF CUSTOMS UNION

JEM081

ADVANCED ECONOMICS OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION:

Microeconomic Aspects

Dr. Wadim Strielkowski IES FSV CUNI

October 7, 2013

(2)

Contents

Traditional partial equilibrium approach to an analysis of customs union

Welfare effects of customs union compared to general tariff protection regime

Customs union: is it always a better arrangement than tariff protection?

Readings:

Baldwin, R, Wyplosz, C.: The Economics of European Integration. McGraw-Hill Higher Education, 2003. Ch.5

Turnovec, F.: Political Economy of European Integration.

Karolinum, Charles University Press, Prague, 2003, Ch. 4.

Viner, J.: Customs Union Issue, 1950.

Pugel, W., International Economics, McGraw Hill, 2003, Chapter 11.

(3)

Customs union

a group of countries among which trade takes

place freely without being restricted by the barriers of tariffs or quotas on trade, and which adopts a

common external tariff - all member countries impose the same tariffs on countries outside the customs union

the theory of customs union - a good example of the relevance of economic theory for practical economic policies

(4)

Customs unions in European history

The best-known customs unions have included the Zollverein, Benelux and the EEC, now called the EU.

The Zollverein was formed by German states in the 1830's. These states became the German nation in 1871.

Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg established Benelux in the 1944.

Belgium, France, Italy, Luxembourg, the

Netherlands and West Germany set up the EEC (EU) in 1957.

(5)

Customs unions related to the EU

EU-Andorra: established in 1991.

EU-San Marino: established in 2002.

EU-Turkey: established in 1996.

(6)

Customs unions in the world

Andean Community (CAN): formed in 1988.

East African Community (EAC): formed in 2005.

Customs Union of Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia:

formed in 2010.

Israel-Palestinian Authority: formed in 1994.

Southern Common Market (MERCOSUR): formed in 1991.

Southern African Customs Union (SACU): formed in 1910 (the oldest still existing CU in the world (RSA, Botswana, Lesotho, Swaziland, Namibia).

Switzerland-Lichtenstein: formed in 1924.

(7)

Customs unions in economic theory

Customs union theory builds on strict assumptions such as perfect competition in commodity and

factor markets and hence it is often referred to as orthodox customs union theory

It also only deals with the static welfare effects of a customs union.

Customs union has both positive and negative welfare effects, compared to a situation in which every member state is practicing protectionism

The theory is relatively new (started in 1950)

(8)

Economic theory of customs union

any economic theory of regional product market integration has to address the question of

economic justification of particular integration

forms (the question whether an arrangement would be superior to the status quo and to participation in world-wide trade liberalisation)

until the beginning of the 1950s it was commonly held that the customs unions and free trade areas were steps promoting free international trade

only after pioneering work of Jacob Viner’s

published in 1950 it was realised that customs unions might as well be seen as a step towards protectionism

(9)

Simple model of a customs union

Elimination of tariffs on imports from member countries

Adoption of a common external tariff on imports from the rest of the world

Apportionment of customs revenue according to an agreed formula

(10)

Simple model of a customs union: assumptions

Pure competition in commodity and factor markets

Factor mobility within countries but not between them

No transportation costs

Tariffs are the only form of trade restrictions

Prices reflect the opportunity costs of production

Trade is balanced

Resources are fully employed

(11)

Viner’s contribution

Jacob Viner (1892-1970) - Canadian economist, professor at Chicago University and Princeton

University, an international trade theorist; his book The Customs Union Issue introduced the

distinction between the trade-creating and the trade-diverting effects of customs unions

contribution of Jacob Viner was an introduction of welfare consideration into the theory of

international trade in general and particularly into the theory of customs unions

(12)

Trade creation and trade diversion

ground-stones of Viner's theory of customs unions are concepts of trade diversion and trade creation effects of different arrangements of regional

integration.

original Viners’ definition of these concepts was formulated in terms of trade flows:

trade diversion: switch in trade from less expensive to more expensive producers

trade creation: switch in trade from more expensive to less expensive producers

(13)

Trade creation and trade diversion

in 1965 Johnson suggested that the concept of

trade diversion and trade creation should be more precisely defined on the basis of welfare effects rather than in terms of trade flows

trade creation - welfare change due to the

replacement of higher cost domestic production and/or higher cost imports by lower-cost imports

trade diversion - welfare change due to the

replacement of imports from a low cost source by imports from a higher cost source

(14)

Trade creation and trade diversion

in terms of world allocation of resources: trade creation is beneficial to welfare, while trade

diversion worsens allocation

a customs union is economically justified if it leads to a trade creation, while a customs union

generating a trade diversion leads towards a

deeper protectionism and decrease of efficiency

(15)

Viner’s model - assumptions

perfect competition in commodity and factors markets,

perfect factor mobility within the individual countries, but not among the countries,

full employment and foreign trade equilibrium,

perfectly price elastic supply on the world market,

economies and/or diseconomies of scale are not considered

(16)

Viner’s model - assumptions

transport costs are not considered,

at least three participants of the trade are

considered; countries A and B, discriminating in trade with the rest of the world, and the world

market,

a partial equilibrium approach is adopted: one commodity markets are considered,

customs union formation will not increase the tariff protection.

(17)

Viner’s model – a small country and a big country

A partial equilibrium model: customs union of a small country and a big country

two countries:

H (home country)

P (potential partner country)

world market W

country H is assumed to be a small country, country P is assumed to be a big country

(18)

Viner’s model – a small country and a big country

a partial market for one commodity

let

SH(p) be a domestic supply function

DH(p) be domestic demand function for this commodity in the country H

the supply by the partner country and the world market supply of the commodity is assumed to be perfectly elastic, hence the country H cannot

influence the price

(19)

19

Viner’s model – initial situation of general tariff protection

let us denote

pW world price

t non-discriminatory tariff

pP the price in the partner country P

pH the closed equilibrium price in the home country

pW+t tariff protected price in H

Assume that

pW < pP < pW+t < pH

Initial situation: the small country H covers part of its domestic demand by tariff protected import

from the world market and considers formation of customs union with big country P

(20)

Country H in general tariff protection regime (before CU

formation)

TP equilibrium Et

EH

d q

s p

p H

W p +t

W

St(q) Sd(q)

Dd(q)

H

t t

Sw(q)

Ew CE equilibrium

FT equilibrium

d

sw q w q

p

pP

(21)

Welfare before CU formation

domestic supply of country H is st,

domestic demand dt and import from the world market at the price pW + t is dt – st

welfare (shaded area in the graph) including

tariff revenues (dt - st)t

.

p

q

(a)

consumers' surplus in TP

producers' surplus in TP

tariff revenues in TP

Et

EH

d q s p

p H

W p +t

W

St(q) Sd(q)

Dd(q)

H

t t

Sw(q)

p P

(22)

Viner’s model – customs union with big country P

assume that country H is considering a possibility of switching from tariff protection to customs

union with the country P

after the customs union is created the trade inside the union will be tariff free, for the price pCU = pP

less than the pW + t

will there be a trade creation or trade diversion, welfare improvement for H compared to tariff protection?

(23)

Country H in customs union with big country P (after CU formation)

E

E

p

s q d q

p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

CU equilibrium

Sw(q) Ew

(24)

Equilibrium in customs union of a small and big country

comparing to tariff protection:

effective supply curve for country H in the customs union will be SCU

domestic equilibrium supply will decrease from st to sCU

domestic equilibrium

demand will expand from dt to dCU

the difference dCU - sCU

represents the import from the country P

equilibrium price will decrease from pW+t to pP

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

CU equilibrium

Sw(q) Ew

(25)

Welfare effects of customs

union of a small and big country

E

E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(26)

Is customs union more beneficial for country H than tariff protection?

welfare effects of customs union formation for small country H

comparing customs union to initial

situation of a general tariff protection regime, is there a welfare gain in

country H?

Comparing customs union to potential

general free trade regime

(27)

Comparison of welfare in CU and TP

p

q

(a)

consumers' surplus in TP

producers' surplus in TP

tariff revenues in TP

Et EH

d q s p

p H

W p +t

W

St(q) Sd(q)

Dd(q)

H

t t

Sw(q)

p P

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(28)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

before the union was

created the country H was importing from the world market for lower price than in the customs union with country P

strictly Vinerian approach classifying such a customs union as purely trade

diverting and, therefore, economically unjustified, is rather misleading and

problematic

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(29)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

together with trade diversion following from increase of

producers’ price we can observe at the same

time a reduction of the more expensive

domestic production in favor of cheaper

imports from partner's country and decrease of domestic supply

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(30)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

The total welfare effect for the

country H:

The decrease of the equilibrium price

from p

W

+ t to p

CU

= p

P

leads to an

increase of

consumers' surplus by the amount equal to regions denoted as (a), (b), (c) and (d)

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(31)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

At the same time producers' surplus is decreasing by an amount equal to the area (a).

The government is losing tariff

revenues equal to the regions (c) and (e)

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d) (e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(32)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

Considering gains and losses we can see that areas (a) and (c) do not represent a gain, they are compensated by losses in producers' surplus and

government tariff

revenues, but only an internal redistribution of welfare between producers and

consumers

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(33)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

the positive welfare effects of the

customs union for the home country

consists of areas (b) and (d). The trade

creation effect was defined by Johnson as a sum of these two areas, reg (b) + reg (d)

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(34)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

Negative welfare effect is given by the region (e), the loss of tariff

revenues, used before for welfare redistribution, by Johnson this

represents a trade diversion effect

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(35)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

the net welfare effect given as

reg(b)+reg(d)-reg(e) indicates, whether the trade creation or the trade diversion prevails in a

particular case of the customs union

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(36)

Trade creation and trade diversion in CU

Conclusion: one can make no

general statement about the total

welfare effects of customs unions, an empirical

investigation of

each particular case is necessary

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(37)

Customs union puzzle: tariff reduction versus customs union

Let before the customs union formation the tariff is t

0

and

p

P

< p+t

0

< p

H

then in the customs union with the country P the country H will import from country P instead from world market

t

0

will remain to be common external tariff

in the customs union

(38)

Customs union equilibrium

E

E

p

s q d q

p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

CU equilibrium

Sw(q) Ew

(39)

Customs union equilibrium and welfare

domestic supply of country H in the customs union will be sCU, domestic demand will be dCU and import from P to H will be dCU – sCU

positive trade creation effect: area (b) and (d), negative trade diversion

effect: area (e), total positive effect if

reg(b) + reg(d) > reg(e)

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff

revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

(40)

What is better: customs union or tariff reduction

let us consider situation when country H decides (instead of forming CU with P) reduce unilaterally tariff protection from original level t0 to the level of price pP, it means that new tariff tn is constructed in such a way that tn=pP-pW

in this case we shall get the same market

equilibrium in country H as in the case of customs union with P: the same domestic supply, domestic demand and import, but import now will come from the world market instead of from country P

is it better or worse than the customs union with P?

(41)

Tariff reduction equilibrium

q

E

EH

d q

s p

p H

W W

Sto(q)

Sd(q) Dd(q)

H

Stn(q) W

to

Etn EW

Eto equilibrium with tariff to

to to

s

tn dd

tn

Sw(q) p

p +to p +tn

Etn equilibrium with tariff tn

(42)

Customs union puzzle: tariff reduction versus customs union

in the customs union tariff protection is abolished in internal union trade

and the government does not collect any tariff revenues

in a new situation with reduced tariff t

n

government tariff revenues will remain on the level of imports multiplied by

tariff

(43)

Welfare of tariff reduction

q

E

EH

d q

s p

p H

W W

Sto(q)

Sd(q)

Dd(q)

H

Stn(q) W

to

Etn

(a) (c)

(e) EW

Welfare effect of tariff reduction from t0 to tn reg(b)+reg(d)+reg(f)+reg(g)

to to

s

tn dd

tn

Sw(q) p

(d) (b)

(f) (g)

p +to p +tn

(44)

Customs union puzzle: tariff reduction versus customs union

Welfare gain of country H due to tariff

reduction to t

n

(compared to the situation of tariff protection with t

0

) corresponds to the areas (b), (d), (f) and (g)

(b)+(d) = increase in consumer surplus

minus loss in producers surplus (a) minus decrease of the government tariff revenues (c) from the original imports

(f)+(g) = increase of government tariff

revenues from extended imports from the

world market

(45)

Welfare in customs union and tariff reduction

E E

p

s q d q p

p

H H

H W

t

t t

consumers' surplus in CU

producers' surplus in CU

no tariff revenues in CU

(a) (b) (c) (d)

(e)

sCU d

CU

Scu(q) Sh(q)

St(q) ECU

p

CU

p

W

+t p

P

=

Sw(q)

q

E

EH

d q s p

p H

W W

Sto(q)

Sd(q)

Dd(q)

H

Stn(q) W

to

Etn

(a) (c)

(e) EW

Welfare effect of tariff reduction from t0 to tn reg(b)+reg(d)+reg(f)+reg(g)

to to

stn dd

tn

Sw(q) p

(d) (b)

(f) (g)

p +to p +tn

(46)

Tariff reduction generates more welfare than customs union

When we compare this result to the welfare effect of customs union with country P, we can conclude that tn < to implies

reg(b)+reg(d)+reg(f)+reg(g)>reg(b)+reg(c)-reg(e)

the right side of inequality represents welfare effect (for country H) of customs union with country p

and the left side represents welfare effect (for

country H) of original tariff reduction t0 the level tn such that pP = pW+tn without entering the customs union with P

(47)

Problems and questions

why the customs unions are created at all, when the theory indicates that the same production and consumption effect and better welfare effect can be achieved by unilateral tariff reduction?

do we have incompetent decision makers or there is something missing in the

theory?

the answers probably should be looked for

in oversimplified structure of the Vinerian's

framework of customs union models

(48)

Some oversimplifications to be removed

Perfect elasticity of partner's country

supply is a rather strong assumption, that is, perhaps, valid for economic relations between San Marino and Italy, but hardly for non-trivial economies.

Customs union has usually measurable effects in both (in our simplified two

country model) or all (in a more general

models) participating countries. Hence the

assumption that export from country P to

country H has no influence on price should

be relaxed

(49)

Some oversimplifications to be removed

Single commodity market assumption is also

rather misleading. Changes in supply, demand and price on one partial market influence also other

partial markets, so multi-commodity analysis can lead to more realistic results

Vinerian’s models analyze only static effects,

ignoring dynamic effects, such as restructuring, economy of scale etc. Firms faced with increased competition will try to lower their costs to stay in the market and increased technical efficiency due to increased competition can have a welfare effect, exceeding many times the limited static effect.

(50)

Model of a customs union of two small countries on one-commodity

market

assume as before two countries H and P, and the world market W

In this case let both countries H and P are small economies, they still face a perfectly elastic world supply curve, but after formation of eventual

customs union of H and P the customs union

supply curve will be the sum of the two domestic supply curves, the customs union demand curve will be the sum of the two domestic demand curves and the customs union equilibrium price will be

different from closed equilibrium prices in the both member countries

(51)

Two small countries supply and demand, closed equilibrium

let

S

H

(p) be a supply function in H D

H

(p) be a demand function in H S

P

(p) be a supply function in P D

P

(p) be a demand function in P

Closed equilibrium (q

H

,p

H

) in H

p

H

: S

H

(p)=D

H

(p), q

H

= S

H

(p

H

)=D

H

(p

H

) Closed equilibrium (q

P

,p

P

) in P

p

P

: S

P

(p)=D

P

(p), q

P

=S

P

(p

P

)=D

P

(p

P

)

(52)

Two small countries supply and demand, closed equilibrium

pP pH

pw

COUNTRY H COUNTRY P

EcH

EcP

qH qP

(53)

Two small countries supply and demand, tariff protection

pP pH

pw

COUNTRY H COUNTRY P

EcH

EcP

qH qP pt

dtH stH

EtH

(54)

Customs unions of H and P, joint supply and demand

Considering customs union of H and P, there will be a free trade among H and P leading to joint equilibrium, and common external tariff for trade protection with

respect of the rest of the world

Supply in customs union: “sum” of two supply functions, demand in customs union: “sum” of two demand functions

What means “sum” in our case?

(55)

Sum of supply and demand functions in H and P

p p p p p

H W+t

P W CU

qCU

q dCU

P P s

P

sCU CU H q

H dCU

H

Country H Country P Customs union of

H and P D D

DP CU

H

S S

S

H

P CU

(56)

Sum of supply functions

Sum of supply functions in H and P

0 0

0 0

0 0

0 0

0 0 min{ , }

( ) ( )

( )

( ) ( ) max{ , }

SH SP

H SH SP

CU

P SP SH

H P SH SP

if p p p

S p if either p p p

S p

S p or p p p

S p S p if p p p

 

(57)

Sum of demand functions in H and P

Sum of demand functions in H and P

0 0

0 0

0 0

0 0

0 max{ , }

( ) ( )

( )

( ) ( ) min{ , }

DH DP

H DP DH

CU

P DH DP

H P DH DP

if p p p

D p if either p p p

D p

D p or p p p

D p D p if p p p

 

(58)

Customs union price

Knowing customs union supply and demand function SCU(p) and DCU(p), we can calculate equilibrium price of customs union pCU of small countries H and P as the solution of equation

( ) ( )

CU CU

S pD p

and comparing it to world price and tariff protected price we can decide whether the customs union of H and P has some justification or not. The necessary condition for welfare increasing customs union of H and P in this case is

CU

<

W

+ t

p p

(59)

Welfare in customs union of two small countries

country H imports from the country P for the price pCU and the welfare effects for country H are given by known formula reg(a)+reg(b)-reg(c), i.e. gain in consumers' surplus minus loss of government tariff revenues

country P is an exclusive exporter into country H and its welfare effect is given by the area (d),

increase in producers' surplus minus decrease of consumers' surplus, which is, under given

assumptions, always positive.

(60)

Welfare in customs union of two small countries

Then the total welfare effect of customs union for the both countries is reg(a)+reg(b)-

reg(c)+reg(d)

Taking into account a bit more realistic case of an influence of

customs union on

market equilibrium in both considered

countries, the total balance of welfare changes increases

(a) (b) (c)

(d)

p p

p p p

country H country P

E

E

H H

W W

P

P CU

+t

q s dP s sq d d

1 1

HH H H H

2 2

P P

1 1

(61)

EXAMPLE

One commodity market in country H with domestic demand and supply functions:

A potential partner country: P

World price: pW = 4

Non-discriminative ad valorem tariff: t = 1

Price in partner country: pP = 4.5

20p

- 370

= D (p)

50p +

50 -

= S (p)

H H

(62)

EXAMPLE

From

we get closed equilibrium price

and closed equilibrium quantity

20p -

370

= 50p +

50 -

6 70 =

= 420 p*

250

= p )

D (

= p )

S (

q*= H * H *

(63)

EXAMPLE

Case 1: Welfare of closed equilibrium

Price of zero demand

Price of zero supply

18.5

= p 0

= 20p -

370

1

= p 0

= 50p +

50

-

(64)

EXAMPLE

Consumers’ surplus

Producers’ surplus

Total welfare in closed equilibrium 1562.5

= 250 6)

- (18.5 2

= 1 CS

625

= 250 1)

- 2(6

= 1 PS

2187.5

= 625 +

1562.5

= PS + CS TW CE =

(65)

65

EXAMPLE

Case 2: Tariff Protection

Tariff protected market price

Domestic demand

Domestic supply

Imports

5

= 1 + 4

= t + p

=

pt w

200

= 5

* 50 + 50 -

= p ) SH( t

270

= 5

* 20 - 370

= ) p DH ( t

70

= 200 -

270

= p )

S ( - p )

DH ( t H t

(66)

EXAMPLE

Consumers’ surplus

Producers’ surplus

Government tariff revenue

1822.5

= 270 5)

- (18.5 2

= 1 CS

400

= 200 1)

- 2(5

= 1 PS

70

= 1

* 70

= TR

(67)

EXAMPLE

Total welfare under tariff protection:

Compared to closed equilibrium consumers are gaining, producers are losing, total welfare

effect is positive.

2292.5

= 70 + 400 +

1822.5

= TR + PS + CS TWTP=

(68)

EXAMPLE

Case 3: Customs Union of H with P

Customs Union market price

Domestic demand

Domestic supply

Imports

4.5 p =

pCU = P

280

= 4.5

* 20 - 370

= ) p

DH ( CU

175

= 4.5

* 50 + 50 -

= ) p

S H ( CU

105

= 175 -

280

= p )

S ( - p )

DH( CU H CU

(69)

EXAMPLE

Consumers’ surplus

Producers’ surplus

Total welfare

1960

= 280 4.5)

- (18.5 2

= 1 CS

306.25

= 175 1)

- 2(4.5

= 1 PS

2266.25

= 306.25 +

1960

= PS + CS TW CU =

(70)

EXAMPLE

Welfare effect of CU compared to tariff protection:

Conclusion: By Viner’s model of customs

union, in this particular case tariff protection is for country H economically more beneficial than customs union.

26.25 -

= 2292.5 -

2266.25

TW = TW -

WECU = CU TC

(71)

71

Likelihood of gains and losses from customs union

The larger is the economic area of the CU and the more numerous are the countries of which it is composed, the greater will be the scope for TC.

It is likely that TC will be greater than TD if

countries joining together in a CU are similar in the range of products they produce before the formation of the union.

This is because TC occurs through the

replacement of domestic production by more efficient production within the union.

If future members produce essentially different goods, there will be little scope for such

replacement and, hence, little trade creation.

Odkazy

Související dokumenty

The impact of Europeanization on Domestic Policy structures: Asylum and refugee policies in Turkey's accession process to the European Union.. Middle East

For example in our simple model of a customs union the customs union of countries 1 and 2 increases total welfare of both countries, but while country 2 is

In the case of stock exchanges, the main Fintech innovation is expected to come from the implementation of the distributed ledger technology or blockchain to run market

In all but one case, this lower bound is given by the union of the intersection of the given line segment with R and its continuation to the right (as defined by (51)).. In the case

Domestic competitive pressure, measured by market structure, and increased import penetration are associated with higher firm performance in Poland irrespective of the

Mohlo by se zdát, že tím, že muži s nízkým vzděláním nereagují na sňatkovou tíseň zvýšenou homogamíí, mnoho neztratí, protože zatímco se u žen pravděpodobnost vstupu

In the case of the Czech trade balance with the rest of the world, the key determinants are the domestic GDP, qualitative upgrading in the unit prices of exports, Czech

The decline in credit card debt associated with higher perceived financial knowledge seems to be contradictory to the findings of Gorbachev and Luengo-Prado (2016).